Example of A Game Without A Value - Game Value

Game Value

Sion and Wolfe show that


\sup_f \inf_g \iint K\,df\,dg=\frac{1}{3}

but


\inf_g \sup_f \iint K\,df\,dg=\frac{3}{7}.

These are the maximal and minimal expectations of the game's value of player I and II respectively.

The and respectively take the supremum and infimum over pdf's on the unit interval (actually Borel probability measures). These represent player I and player II's (mixed) strategies. Thus, player I can assure himself of a payoff of at least 3/7 if he knows player II's strategy; and player II can hold the payoff down to 1/3 if he knows player I's strategy.

There is clearly no epsilon equilibrium for sufficiently small, specifically, if . Dasgupta and Maskin assert that the game values are achieved if player I puts probability weight only on the set and player II puts weight only on .

Glicksberg's theorem shows that any zero-sum game with upper or lower semicontinuous payoff function has a value (in this context, an upper (lower) semicontinuous function K is one in which the set (resp ) is open for any real c).

Observe that the payoff function of Sion and Wolfe's example is clearly not semicontinuous. However, it may be made so by changing the value of K(x, x) and K(x, x + 1/2) to either +1 or −1, making the payoff upper or lower semicontinuous respectively. If this is done, the game then has a value.

Read more about this topic:  Example Of A Game Without A Value

Famous quotes containing the word game:

    One of life’s primal situations; the game of hide and seek. Oh, the delicious thrill of hiding while the others come looking for you, the delicious terror of being discovered, but what panic when, after a long search, the others abandon you! You mustn’t hide too well. You mustn’t be too good at the game. The player must never be bigger than the game itself.
    Jean Baudrillard (b. 1929)

    People’s affections can be as thin as paper; life is like a game of chess, changing with each move.
    Chinese proverb.